Our society is fundamentally changing. These days, almost nothing works without a computer chip. Processing power doubles every 18 months and will exceed the capabilities of human brains in about ten years from now. Some time ago, IBM's Big Blue computer already beat the best chess player. Meanwhile, computers perform about 70 percent of all financial transactions, and IBM's Watson advises customers better than human telephone hotlines. Will computers and robots soon replace skilled labour? In many European countries, unemployment is reaching historical heights. The forthcoming economic and social impact of future information and communication technologies (ICT) will be huge - probably more significant than that caused by the steam engine, or by nano- or biotechnology.
The storage capacity for data is growing even faster than computational capacity. Within just a year we will soon generate more data than in the entire history of humankind. The "Internet of Things" will network trillions of sensors. Unimaginable amounts of data will be collected. Big Data is already being praised as the “oil of the 21st century”. What opportunities and risks does this create for our society, economy, and environment?
From "homo economicus" to "homo socialis", the networked decision-maker
Let's start by analysing the situation today. Probably, the most widespread economic paradigm is that of "homo economicus", who merely tries to maximize personal benefits. It is often believed that such behaviour balances and coordinates the interests of individuals, as if controlled by an "invisible hand" and automatically maximizes social welfare.
If one believes in this neoclassical credo, then, economic problems arise mainly from the fact that there are too many regulations, or that some people do not adhere to the principle of self-regarding optimization. But why are there so many regulations, and why do many people have fairness preferences?
It was long believed that the merciless forces of evolution and natural selection could not have created man other than as a selfish being. However, recent scientific insights teach us something else. It has been demonstrated that the very same evolutionary forces that create "homo economicus" may also produce a different kind of people under very realistic circumstances: "homo socialis". "Homo socialis" tries to reach favourable outcomes as well, but considers the impact on others when taking decisions. As a consequence, "homo socialis" does not decide in an independent, but rather in an interdependent, "networked" fashion. This has surprising consequences: while "homo economicus" often runs into "tragedies of the commons", for example, the exploitation and pollution of the environment, overfishing and/or global warming, "homo socialis" can overcome such problems and reach a higher success by conditional cooperativeness.
Reputation systems to master social dilemmas
The above tragedies of the commons result from social dilemmas. These are situations, in which it would be good for everyone, if everybody behaved cooperatively, but where there is also a temptation to take advantage of the cooperativeness of others. Under such conditions, cooperation is likely to erode. To avoid this, it is common to establish regulations and enforce compliance with them by means of monitoring and punishment strategies. However, over time, the costs of such strategies have created enormous public debts, and in some cases de facto state bankruptcy.
How to envisage a self-regulating market system? The transfer of the principle of Swiss-style bottom-up democracy to the business world would probably be a good way to imagine this.
What would be suitable institutions for "homo socialis"? It is known that social dilemmas can be overcome by various social mechanisms, such as genetic favouritism, direct reciprocity ("you help me, I help you"), or punishment of uncooperative behaviour. Genetic favouritism tends to create ethnic conflicts between tribes, while direct reciprocity may promote corruption. The punishment of non-cooperative behaviour corresponds to our current approach, but this seems to have reached the limits of feasibility and affordability. Note, however, that there is a further approach, which transfers the success principle of social communities to the context of the "global village", namely reputation.
"Prosumers" and "qualified money"
The Information Age will transform markets fundamentally. In the following, I will outline just some aspects of the now emerging "democratic, participatory market societies." Flexible self-organization will play a much bigger role than today. The emergence of "Prosumers" illustrates this. These are consumers who participate in the production of the products they buy. Instead of just selecting existing products from a catalogue or choosing the special features of a personalized car, consumers will be able to create new components of products, new designs, or even entirely new products. For example, they could use a 3D printer to produce their own cell phone cover and distribute it to others. Or they could come up with their own fashion and upload it to a company webpage to produce it for them, their family, friends, and colleagues, or indeed customers all over the world. People could also distribute their own books, their own music and their own movies. Or they could put a team together to construct more sophisticated products.
An "innovation ecosystem" of flexible "projects"
However, Europe has not found its place in this new innovation universe, yet. Suitable institutions must first be established: the aforementioned reputation system is just one of them. Furthermore, open platforms are needed to enable participation and cooperation. In order to encourage an open exchange of information and the emergence of an innovation ecosystem, new incentive systems are required, which reward creative contributions. For this, the relevance of innovations must be made measureable, and inventors must be compensated for the use their ideas, e.g. with micropayments. Last but not least, we need a new science, which helps us to understand and create the participatory market society. While current economics ("economics 1.0") is tailored to "homo economicus", the emerging "economics 2.0" must be tailored to "homo socialis", the networked decision-maker. These and further institutions should be part of a far-reaching strategy to create an "innovation accelerator".
An age of creativity and participation is ahead of us. We just have to use the opportunities that modern information and communication technologies offer. Reputation systems and social media can promote awareness of the risks and benefits of our available decision alternatives. In particular, they can help us to address challenges such as global warming and other problems in a more cooperative and sustainable way.
References
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.